League cooperation necessary for fair play
This is an excerpt from Sport and Public Policy by Charles Santo & Gerard Mildner.
From the beginning, competitors in organized sports have cooperated with one another to ensure order and provide a marketable product. A natural outgrowth of associations between individual franchises, leagues have enhanced the viability and stability of their professional sports by providing structure and ensuring an even field for competition.
Setting Rules and Schedules
The early years of British soccer and American college football were often played under “house rules” determined by the host team, which sometimes led to chaotic disputes and violent outcomes. Concerned by some of the extreme events, college presidents unified the rules of college football and instituted a number of measures to ensure the safety of players. The colleges hired impartial third-party referees to allow each team to participate under conditions of fair play.
As professional sports developed, league organizations established common rules of play so that fans could understand the game and teams could prepare for the next game without worrying that the rules would be tailored to help the home team.
A second reason for sport leagues to organize is the need to arrange a schedule among participating teams. Unlike other fields of commerce, each sport team needs to meet its rivals, so some coordinating authority must arrange a schedule of games. Moreover, fans find interest in the determination of the best team in that sport through a league table or league championship. For such a champion to be determined in a fair way, each participating team should play the other teams in their league in an equal or near equal number of circumstances.
Competitive Balance
Sport fans draw interest from seeing sporting events in which the outcome is uncertain and the strength of each team is more or less balanced. In practice, the intervention required for a league to ensure that the teams within the league have a competitive balance is extensive. For most of the 20th century, however, sport leagues did not make a great effort to ensure competitive balance. Dynasties thus emerged, such as the New York Yankees in baseball (winners of 6 American League titles between 1921 and 1928 and 8 World Series titles between 1947 and 1958) and the Boston Celtics in basketball (winners of 10 NBA championships between 1959 and 1969).
One can argue that competitive balance within a league is not necessary to draw fan interest to a sport, as evidenced by the attendance figures in baseball and basketball during the era of the Yankees' and Celtics' dominance. Dynasties create familiar players and story lines for fans to follow. More recently, the emergence of fantasy sport leagues has allowed fans to follow a game focused on the statistical performance of players whom they “own” rather than the outcome of the game itself.
Nevertheless, a number of innovations to improve league competitive balance have been created in recent decades. For example, consider the following:
- Order of the draft. One of the first innovations was the creation of the reverse-order-of-finish player draft, which allows the previous year's worst team to have the first choice among new players entering the league. To some extent, this system promotes equality of teams over time.
- Unequal schedules. The National Football League (NFL) has implemented a policy of unequal schedules (challenging one of the foundations for league organization described earlier) to create greater uncertainty in league outcomes. Schedules are drawn so that the division-winning teams of the previous year play other division winners more often, and last-place teams play each other more often as well. This policy enhances the likelihood that weaker teams will have better win-loss records and helps the league schedule a greater number of compelling matchups than would be generated by a random schedule.
- Revenue sharing. Dominance and dynasties emerge in part because teams in larger cities have access to more revenue than do teams in smaller cities; they can sell more tickets at higher prices and charge higher prices to television networks that want to broadcast their games. To mitigate this potential imbalance, some leagues have established procedures to redistribute revenue from rich teams to poor teams or to provide equal shares of revenue that is generated at a leaguewide level. For example, current league agreements in Major League Baseball require that each team contribute 31 percent of its local revenue (which includes revenue from broadcast contracts and ticket sales) to a common pool that is then redistributed evenly to all teams in the league. The largest source of revenue for NFL teams is television broadcast rights. In the NFL, contracts for broadcast rights are negotiated directly between the league as whole and national networks, rather than between individual teams and their local networks. This policy allows the league to distribute the revenue evenly to all teams regardless of their market size.
- Salary caps. Several leagues also implement salary caps, which limit the amount of money that each team can spend on player payroll, to ensure that teams in larger markets (or with wealthier owners) cannot simply buy up all the best talent by outspending smaller-market teams. Luxury taxes, which are levied as a financial penalty on teams with payrolls above a certain threshold, are designed to serve a similar purpose.
Many critics of professional sport leagues view their obsession with competitive balance in recent years as more of an attempt to increase firm profitability by gaining an economic advantage over players in labor negotiations or by gaining advantage over broadcasting companies in the market for broadcasting rights. In addition, revenue-sharing agreements can often create perverse incentives for teams to lose. A team owner with a low payroll often stands to gain more in profit from revenue-sharing redistribution than he or she might by making the kind of payroll increases necessary to field a winning team.
Downside of Cooperation
At some level, leagues play a benign and beneficial role as a convener of events and guarantor of fair play. Although we accept that the home team has the advantage of its partisan crowd and its familiarity with the home stadium, no one would accept today having the home team hire the referees, pick which ball should be used, or establish the penalties for fouls. But sport leagues also present a troubling set of contradictions. Although leagues allow owners to work together to promote fair play and balanced competition between member teams, they simultaneously allow competing business people to collude with one another to gain control over individual players, squash any competition that might emerge from rival leagues, and exert influence over fans and city finances through market power. Such collusion among entities who are otherwise competitors is a hallmark characteristic of a cartel. Therefore, sport leagues also represent a contradiction in American public policy because their monopolistic operations are aberrations in the face of antitrust law. This contradiction has been enabled by a series of judicial and congressional precedents, which are summarized in table 1.1 and are discussed in detail throughout the remainder of this chapter.
Court case or congressional action |
Year | Issues involved |
Impetus | Outcome or effect |
Federal Baseball Club of Baltimore v. National League of Professional Baseball Clubs |
1922 | Alleged antitrust activities of Organized Baseball |
The Baltimore franchise of the Federal League sued the American and National Leagues when the Federal League failed, leaving Baltimore without a professional team. |
The Supreme Court ruled that Organized Baseball did not qualify as an illegal monopoly, declaring that baseball was inherently neither interstate nor commerce. Baseball seemed to have been given an exemption from antitrust law. |
Congressional Subcommittee on the Study of Monopoly Power Hearings |
1951 | Alleged antitrust activities of Major League Baseball |
Congress considered granting a blanket exemption to Major League Baseball to protect it from pending antitrust lawsuits. |
Not willing to support the “baseball monopoly,” Congress refused to take any action, leaving it to the courts to decide the legality of baseball's actions. Congress' inaction, however, was seen as an endorsement of baseball's antitrust exemption. |
Toolson v. New York Yankees |
1953 | Baseball's reserve clause and antitrust activities |
A player in the New York Yankees franchise opposed a demotion and sued the team and the league, charging that their monopolistic practices were an illegal restraint of trade. |
The Supreme Court reaffirmed baseball's antitrust exemption, citing the exemption given the sport in the Federal case and Congress' inaction in 1951. |
United States v. International Boxing Club of New York |
1955 | Alleged antitrust activities of a professional boxing club |
The federal government charged the International Boxing club of New York with being an illegal monopoly on the grounds that it controlled boxing exhibitions and broadcasts in various states. |
The Supreme Court ruled the International Boxing Club an illegal monopoly and declared that baseball's antitrust exemption did not apply to other sports. |
Radovich v. National Football League |
1957 | Football's reserve clause and alleged antitrust activities |
William Radovich, a former NFL player, sued the league when he was blacklisted after leaving the NFL to play for a team in a rival league. |
The Supreme Court declared the NFL's reserve clause illegal under antitrust laws. Baseball's exemption did not apply to other sports leagues. |
Sports Broadcasting Act |
1961 | Congressional protection for sports' leagues controls over broadcasting |
Sports leagues sought special protection from antitrust laws so that they could negotiate broadcast contracts for their member teams. |
Congress began setting parameters on acceptable monopolistic activities, proving willing to grant exemptions for favorable reasons. |
NFL-AFL Merger | 1966 | Congressional protection for football leagues to merge and set up a football cartel |
The National Football League and American Football League sought approval to merge into one league, eliminating competition in professional football. |
Congress approved the merger, largely because of popular interest for a unified league championship (the Super Bowl). Congress, however, later rejected a proposed merger between the National Basketball Association and the American Basketball Association in 1971. |
Mackey v. National Football League |
1976 | The legality of the “Rozelle Rule,” a football policy designed to restrict free agency |
A policy requiring a team to give up players if it signs a free agent from another team was challenged as an illegal restraint on trade. |
A district court ruled the “Rozelle Rule” illegal, supporting free agency in football and other professional sports. Courts proved willing to support players' challenges to sport cartels' powers. |
Smith v. Pro Football |
1976 | The legality of football's player draft |
The college player draft was challenged as an illegal restraint on trade. |
A district court ruled the draft system an illegal limitation on an athlete's opportunities and salaries, but the draft was preserved as part of a collective bargaining agreement. |
L.A. Memorial Coliseum v. National Football League |
1984 | The right of an owner to move his franchise |
Unhappy with his stadium deal, Oakland Raiders owner Al Davis sued the NFL for the right to move his franchise to Los Angeles. |
A district court ruled it illegal for a sports league to prevent one of its member owners from moving his franchise, asserting some power for owners and paving the way for franchises to move freely at their owners' desires. |
Learn more about Sport and Public Policy.
More Excerpts From Sport and Public PolicySHOP
Get the latest insights with regular newsletters, plus periodic product information and special insider offers.
JOIN NOW
Latest Posts
- What is the Sport Concussion Assessment Tool 6 (SCAT6)?
- Why are Patient-Reported Outcome Measures (PROMs) important?
- Special tests in injury examination
- See how the muscles work to create ambulation
- Considerations for Activities of Daily Living (ADL) and healing
- Physical properties and principles of water and aquatic exercise